In 1962 the RCP (Royal College of Physicians) published
a Report on Smoking and
health in
the UK. Using research by Sir Richard Doll and Sir Austin Bradford Hill, the
Report established conclusively the link between smoking - including passive
smoking - and lung cancer, other lung diseases, heart disease and
gastrointestinal illnesses. It caused a sensation, and received an ambivalent,
often hostile response from the media, governments and society. In 1962 tobacco
"smoking was omnipresent, accepted, established." "[In the UK]
around 70% of men and 40% of women smoked". It was "a world
suffocated by the swirling clouds of tobacco" - "in pubs, cinemas,
trains, buses, on the streets, and even in hospitals and schools." [from
the RCP-Royal College of Physicians report on Fifty years since Smoking and Health – progress, lessons and priorities for a smoke-free UK,
2012].
Gradually government action reduced this
phenomenon. By 2012
"... smoking is no longer the norm. Our
schools, hospitals, pubs, cinemas and public transport are subject to
smoke-free legislation. [In the UK] Only 21% of the population smokes.
Government, media and society have largely accepted the need to protect people,
particularly children, from much of the harm associated with tobacco
smoke." Still, in the UK it took fifty years to achieve such a large
reduction in smoking incidence. Smokers are still 21% of the population too
many, they represent glaring evidence of either irrationality or addiction or
both, and the persistence of vested interests by tobacco and cigarettes
producers.
Austerity - aiming at a balanced government budget,
reducing expenditure and raising taxation even in the middle of an economic recession
- also has been the norm for a very long time, and still is enshrined in the
statutory policies of EU and EMU, of IMF and ECB. Yet we have known at least
since 1936 (with the publication of Keynes' General
Theory), indeed since 1933-35 (the dates of Michal Kalecki's anticipations
of Keynesian propositions, see Robinson 1976 and Nuti 2004) that austerity can
cause unnecessary, involuntary unemployment of labour and irreversible losses
of income and consumption.
In our time and age austerity is more incomprehensible
than smoking, were it not for the irrational fear of inflation in the middle of
a recession, the generalised addiction to hyper-liberal ideologies and the
vested interests of those who think they benefit from labour unemployment
keeping workers "in their place". What is worse, austerity today is
much more widespread than smoking, it is on the rise and is officially supported
by our national and international authorities more than it ever was, while at
least smoking is steadily declining not least because of progressive health
policies worldwide.
Feasible full employment
Feasible full employment
In 1943 Michael Kalecki could write that “A solid
majority of economists is now of the opinion that, even in a capitalist system,
full employment may be secured by a government spending programme, provided
there is in existence adequate plant to employ all existing labour power, and
provided adequate supplies of necessary foreign raw-materials may be obtained
in exchange for exports”. As long, of course, as such government spending
programme is “financed by borrowing and not by taxation”. Kalecki even dealt
with the case of highly indebted countries, which also could afford and attract
loans to finance government expenditure as long as interest was paid out of a
capital levy.
Opposition to such a policy of full (meaning high and
stable) employment would be political: "(i) opposition in principle to
government spending based on a budget deficit; (ii) opposition to this spending
being directed either towards public investment – which may foreshadow the
intrusion of the state into the new spheres of economic activity – or towards
subsidizing mass consumption; iii) opposition to maintaining full employment
and not merely preventing deep and prolongued slumps”. Such objections subside
in the slump, and are revived in the boom, thus generating what Kalecki called
a "political cycle" and a generally lower average degree of
employment over such cycle than otherwise feasible.
But the feasibility of Kaleckian-Keynesian full
employment policies soon ceased to enjoy the support of a "solid majority
of economists". The effectiveness of expansionary fiscal policy was
challenged on an escalation of arguments.
From
deficit
spending to
expansionary fiscal consolidation
First, it was argued that government expenditure would
“crowd out” private investment. This idea neglects the possibility of private
investment on the contrary “crowding in” additional expenditure due to the
activation of its accelerator effect of higher primary demand. On the contrary, Dennis Robertson (in a talk
given at Princeton in 1953) argued that at least some of the additional savings
out of the income generated by government spending would not represent a
leakage but would be channeled into additional investment, and called this “the
Kalecki effect”.
Second, Ricardian equivalence was invoked, tentatively
put forward by David Ricardo in the early 19th century and re-discovered by Robert J. Barro
in 1974. When government expenditure is raised, funded by borrowing, economic
agents discount the future payments of higher taxes that they anticipate having
to pay to service the higher debt. The effect is the same as it would be if
expenditure was funded directly by an immediate higher tax: lower private
consumption offsetting higher government expenditure. (The reader is invited to
perform a mental experiment: is this how he/she responds to a fiscal stimulus
by the government? I certainly don't).
Third, in the early ‘seventies the theory of so-called
rational expectations was introduced by Robert Lucas and others, which was a
tendentious misnomer. They should have been called expectations successful
by definition. The efficient utilization of all information available, by
all economic agents, makes markets efficient. Nobody is ever surprised.
Multipliers could then be lower than unity.
Fourth, in the 1990s and 2000s a series of empirical
studies propounded the idea of “Expansionary Fiscal Contraction”. They argued
that closing the budget deficit via
higher taxes and/or lower expenditure can be and by and large is expansionary:
see Giavazzi and Pagano (1990, 1996); Alesina and Perotti (1997); Alesina and
Ardagna (2010). Blanchard (1990, then Professor at MIT, before joining the IMF
as Chief Economist in 2008) explained how this was due to the promotion of
private sector-led growth, for the reasons already mentioned above: Ricardian
equivalence, increasing confidence, a favourable impact on expectations,
declining borrowing costs, a weaker currency. This would hold also for "extreme"
fiscal contraction or consolidation.
Growth in a Time of Debt
But the culmination of the expansionary fiscal
consolidation thesis, supported by the so-called "austerians"' -
"advocates of fiscal austerity, of immediate sharp cuts in government spending"
(Krugman's definition) - is a paper by Harvard economists Carmen Reinhart and
Kenneth Rogoff, "Growth in a
Time of Debt" (2010). On the basis of a new dataset of forty-four countries
spanning about two hundred years, incorporating “over 3,700 annual observations
covering a wide range of political systems, institutions, exchange rate
arrangements, and historic circumstances”, Reinhart and Rogoff find that “the
relationship between government debt and real GDP growth is weak for debt/GDP
ratios below a threshold of 90 percent of GDP. Above 90 percent, median growth
rates fall by one percent, and average growth falls considerably
more.”
The notion that government debt exceeding 90 percent of
GDP has a significant negative effect on economic growth became a decisive
supportive argument for austerity by national and international leaders, from
ex-vice-presidential candidate Paul Ryan, chairman of the USA Congress budget
committee, to EC Commissioner Olli Rehn, and authoritative commentators. Thus
Keynes's proposition that “the boom, not the slump, is the right time for
austerity” was falsified, austerity becoming a good policy for all seasons in
highly indebted countries.
The tide is turning
The proposition of
"Expansionary Fiscal Consolidation" was immediately subjected to many
criticisms and was gradually discredited both on theoretical and on empirical
grounds.
Already in November 2008
the IMF Managing Director Dominique Strauss-Kahn took the initiative for a
sizeable global fiscal stimulus of the order of 2% of Global GDP. In an
interview with IMF Survey Online on
29 December 2008 Olivier Blanchard – by then IMF Chief Economist, and Carlo
Cottarelli, Chief of the IMF Fiscal Affairs Department, called for bank
recapitalization (time consuming) and monetary expansion (ineffective at low
interest rates) and made a strong case for fiscal stimulus: "In normal
times, the Fund would indeed be recommending to many countries that they reduce
their budget deficit and their public debt. But these are not normal times, and
the balance of risks today is very different"… "If no fiscal stimulus
is implemented, then demand may continue to fall. And with it, we may see some
of the vicious cycles we have seen in the past: deflation and liquidity traps,
expectations becoming more and more pessimistic and, as a result, a deeper and
deeper recession. If, instead, a fiscal stimulus is implemented but proves
unnecessary, the risk is that the economy recovers too fast. Surely, this risk
is easier to control than the risk of an ever deepening recession." The
IMF raised its lending, increased its own resources and relaxed somewhat its
conditionality, but its commitment was intermittent and short lived. The ECB,
under the leadership of Jean-Claude Trichet, soon was advocating an early exit
strategy from both monetary expansion and fiscal stimulus.
In October 2010, Chapter 3
of the IMF World Economic Outlook examined “the effects of fiscal consolidation
— tax hikes and government spending cuts—on economic activity.” It found that
fiscal consolidation typically reduces output and raises unemployment in the
short term, especially if it occurs simultaneously across many countries, and
if monetary policy is not in a position to offset them. Only in the longer
term, can interest rate cuts, a fall in the value of the currency, and a rise
in net exports usually “soften” but do not offset the contractionary impact.
Baker (2010) criticises
Alesina and others (1995, 2006) for their use of cyclically adjusted deficits,
while policy driven deficit adjustments behave in a keynesian fashion. He also
criticises Broadbent and Daly (2010) on the ground that known cases of
expansionary consolidation occurred for very narrow output gaps relatively to
the large ones that occur in the current crisis.
The September 2011 IMF Fiscal Monitor warned that “too rapid consolidation during 2012 could exacerbate downside risks”: “Further tightening during a downturn could exacerbate rather than alleviate market tensions through its negative impact on growth”.
The September 2011 IMF Fiscal Monitor warned that “too rapid consolidation during 2012 could exacerbate downside risks”: “Further tightening during a downturn could exacerbate rather than alleviate market tensions through its negative impact on growth”.
In 2012 Carlo Cottarelli
stressed the “schizophrenic” attitude of investors with regard to fiscal
consolidation manoeuvres: their initial enthusiasm is followed by the fear of
consequent recession, so that governments are “damned if they do, damned if
they don’t”.
The IMF World Economic Outlook (October 2012) contains a large Box by its Chief Economist Olivier Blanchard and Daniel Leigh arguing that fiscal multipliers have been under-estimated by IMF forecasts and policy documents, by the OECD and the European Commission. Recent IMF research suggests that fiscal multipliers are in the range 0.9 to 1.7, rather than the customary assumption of their being around 0.5. In other words, the cost of fiscal consolidation has been grossly under-estimated. In January 2013 Blanchard and Leigh presented a longer paper expanding their argument at the American Economic Association Annual Conference. However, according to the auhors “More research is needed.”
The IMF World Economic Outlook (October 2012) contains a large Box by its Chief Economist Olivier Blanchard and Daniel Leigh arguing that fiscal multipliers have been under-estimated by IMF forecasts and policy documents, by the OECD and the European Commission. Recent IMF research suggests that fiscal multipliers are in the range 0.9 to 1.7, rather than the customary assumption of their being around 0.5. In other words, the cost of fiscal consolidation has been grossly under-estimated. In January 2013 Blanchard and Leigh presented a longer paper expanding their argument at the American Economic Association Annual Conference. However, according to the auhors “More research is needed.”
But more research was already available to the IMF: Guajardo, Leigh and Pescatori (2011)
investigated "the short-term effects of fiscal consolidation on economic
activity in OECD economies." "We examine the historical record,
including Budget Speeches and IMF documents, to identify changes in fiscal
policy motivated by a desire to reduce the budget deficit and not by responding
to prospective economic conditions. Using this new dataset, our estimates
suggest fiscal consolidation has contractionary effects on private domestic
demand and GDP. By contrast, estimates based on conventional measures of the
fiscal policy stance used in the literature support the expansionary fiscal
contractions hypothesis but appear to be biased toward overstating expansionary
effects.”
And Batini-Callegari-Melina (2012)
- discredit the need for cutting public/social expenditure, for especially in a downturn expenditure multipliers can be up to ten times larger than tax multipliers;
- find absolute values for multipliers of the order of 2.5 instead of 0.9-1.7 as in the IMF World Economic Outlook (2012);
- find aggressive consolidation much more expensive than gradual in terms of GDP.
- discredit the need for cutting public/social expenditure, for especially in a downturn expenditure multipliers can be up to ten times larger than tax multipliers;
- find absolute values for multipliers of the order of 2.5 instead of 0.9-1.7 as in the IMF World Economic Outlook (2012);
- find aggressive consolidation much more expensive than gradual in terms of GDP.
In
May 2013 Jeffrey Frankel criticized various papers by Alesina and other
co-authors (Giavazzi, Ardagna and Favero), all claiming that fiscal consolidation
is not contractionary in a recession. Frankel’s objections are based on a
recent paper by Alesina's original coauthor, Perotti, criticizing the dating
methodology used, and pointing out that some of the fiscal consolidations used
by Alesina et al. were announced by governments but never implemented. Thus
Frankel concludes that Alesina "has not been receiving his fair share of
abuse” (Eurointelligence.com, 22/5/2013).
At
the same time Alesina and Giavazzi softened very considerably their original
position. In May 2013 they actually recommended the Italian government to
overstep the 3% deficit threshold for two years – for “that three per cent
should not be a taboo” – offering the EC in exchange immediate tax reductions on labour incomes
and planned gradual and permanent expenditure cuts in the following three
years. The European Commission would not close the excess deficit procedure for
Italy at end-May but should be willing to approve such plan and verify its
implementation. At the same time, credit to households and enterprises should
resume through bank re-capitalisation conditionally funded by the EMS.
The non-existent 90% threshold
The Reinhert-Rogoff notion of a critical 90% threshold of the debt/GDP ratio was immediately criticized by Irons and Bivens (2010) who argued that causation run backwards, in that slower growth leads to higher debt-to-GDP ratios rather than the other way round. Moreover “there is no compelling reason to believe … that gross debt of about 90% will necessarily lead to slower economic growth… In fact, the greatest threat to economic growth is policy inaction fueled by deficit fears.”
The final blow to the Reinhart-Rogoff 90% debt/GDP dogma came from Herndon, Ash and Pollin (2013), who replicated the analysis by Reinhart and Rogoff 2010 using the original data. Apart from a coding error, which made only a small contribution to their conclusions, Reinhart-Rogoff selectively excluded available data for several Allied nations—Canada, New Zealand, and Australia—that emerged from World War II with high debt but nonetheless exhibited solid growth. And summary statistics were all weighted equally regardless of the duration of high debt and growth performance. Herndon et al. (2013) conclude that “… when properly calculated, the average real GDP growth rate for countries carrying a public-debt-to-GDP ratio of over 90 percent is actually 2.2 percent, not 0.1 percent as published in Reinhart and Rogoff”. It turns out that “average GDP growth at public debt/GDP ratios over 90 percent is not dramatically different than when debt/GDP ratios are lower.”
Reinhart and Rogoff (2013) admitted some of their errors and omissions but argued that these do not alter their ultimate austerity-justifying conclusion: excessive debt depresses growth. But two subsequent studies have claimed that, on the contrary, slow growth appears to cause higher debt (as Irons and Bivens 2010 had already argued). Dube (2013) finds that growth tends to be slower in the five years before countries have high debt levels. In the five years after they have high debt levels, there is no noticeable difference in growth at all, certainly not at the 90 percent debt-to-GDP level regarded by Reinhart and Rogoff as the threshold of non-sustainability. Kimball and Wang (2013) present similar findings. This point is accepted by Reinhart-Rogoff (2013): "The frontier question for research is the issue of causality."
The non-existent 90% threshold
The Reinhert-Rogoff notion of a critical 90% threshold of the debt/GDP ratio was immediately criticized by Irons and Bivens (2010) who argued that causation run backwards, in that slower growth leads to higher debt-to-GDP ratios rather than the other way round. Moreover “there is no compelling reason to believe … that gross debt of about 90% will necessarily lead to slower economic growth… In fact, the greatest threat to economic growth is policy inaction fueled by deficit fears.”
The final blow to the Reinhart-Rogoff 90% debt/GDP dogma came from Herndon, Ash and Pollin (2013), who replicated the analysis by Reinhart and Rogoff 2010 using the original data. Apart from a coding error, which made only a small contribution to their conclusions, Reinhart-Rogoff selectively excluded available data for several Allied nations—Canada, New Zealand, and Australia—that emerged from World War II with high debt but nonetheless exhibited solid growth. And summary statistics were all weighted equally regardless of the duration of high debt and growth performance. Herndon et al. (2013) conclude that “… when properly calculated, the average real GDP growth rate for countries carrying a public-debt-to-GDP ratio of over 90 percent is actually 2.2 percent, not 0.1 percent as published in Reinhart and Rogoff”. It turns out that “average GDP growth at public debt/GDP ratios over 90 percent is not dramatically different than when debt/GDP ratios are lower.”
Reinhart and Rogoff (2013) admitted some of their errors and omissions but argued that these do not alter their ultimate austerity-justifying conclusion: excessive debt depresses growth. But two subsequent studies have claimed that, on the contrary, slow growth appears to cause higher debt (as Irons and Bivens 2010 had already argued). Dube (2013) finds that growth tends to be slower in the five years before countries have high debt levels. In the five years after they have high debt levels, there is no noticeable difference in growth at all, certainly not at the 90 percent debt-to-GDP level regarded by Reinhart and Rogoff as the threshold of non-sustainability. Kimball and Wang (2013) present similar findings. This point is accepted by Reinhart-Rogoff (2013): "The frontier question for research is the issue of causality."
But suicidal policies persist
Such an amazing, cumulative and final discrediting of the alleged expansionary (severe at that) fiscal contraction approach, and the associated 90% threshold to debt sustainability, does not appear to have had much impact on actual policies, especially on German-led European policies, with EU and especially EMU countries tied to the "suicide pact" (Joseph Stiglitz) of so-called Growth and Stability.
Such an amazing, cumulative and final discrediting of the alleged expansionary (severe at that) fiscal contraction approach, and the associated 90% threshold to debt sustainability, does not appear to have had much impact on actual policies, especially on German-led European policies, with EU and especially EMU countries tied to the "suicide pact" (Joseph Stiglitz) of so-called Growth and Stability.
The latest EU Fiscal
Compact or TSCG – Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance – demanded a
balanced budget provision to be inserted in member states’ national
constitutions, subject to a maximum structural deficit of 0.5% of GDP. There
are penalties and automatic adjustments in case of inobservance, subject to the
verification and rulings of the European Court of Justice. Financial assistance
programmes under the ESM – the European Stability Mechanism that come into
operation in March 2012 – from March 2013 are conditional on prior TSGC
ratification.
From 2015 countries
exceeding the statutory debt/GDP ceiling of 60%, required by both the
Maastricht Treaty and the Stability and Growth Pact, are expected to reduce the
excess debt by 1/20 of the current gap every year until the ceiling is reached
– which for a country like Italy at over 130% involves a budgetary surplus of
over 3.5% a year for 20 years.
The IMF (2013) Report criticized
the Troika’s [EC, ECB, IMF] handling of the Greek crisis over the last four
years, but concluded that all was for the best and their policies would not be
any different today in the same circumstances. In July 2013 a conference of
German economists advocated that a debt/GDP ratio of 90% - Reinhart and
Rogoff’s fated but dubious threshold – should trigger off automatic debt
re-structuring and bail-in.
Austerity is like
compulsory smoking
In conclusion, the Keynesian-Kaleckian view of capitalist dynamics is
alive and well. The IMF itself has been reviving it and providing theoretical
and empirical backing for it, by stressing the high cost of fiscal
consolidation, but at the same time continuing to officially recommend and
impose such fiscal consolidation. While providing the strongest case for a
fiscal stimulus, IMF research is being used even by their more enlightened
officials to recommend gradual rather than abrupt fiscal consolidation, instead
of the fiscal stimulus that would be appropriately needed. Obstacles to full
employment policies are still of a political nature today (resistance to a
capital tax to service exceptionally high sovereign debt, in addition to the
drive to maintain workers’ discipline through unemployment). The time for a Kaleckian
(and Keynesian) over-due revival is now, but until it takes place we are all
condemned to suffer from the impoverishment and the unemployment caused by the
deepest, man-made, economic crisis in human history.
REFERENCES
Alesina, A. and R. Perotti
(1995). “Fiscal Expansion and Adjustments in OECD Economies”, Economic
Policy, 207-247.
Alesina, A., S. Ardagna, and
F. Trebbi (2006), “Who Adjusts and When? The Political Economy of Reform”, IMF
Staff Papers, V. 53 Special Issue, Washington.
Alesina
Alberto and Francesco Giavazzi, (2013), “Crescita, una proposta alternativa: Quel tre per cento non sia un tabù”, Corriere della Sera, 17 May.
Baker Dean (2010), “The Myth
of Expansionary Fiscal Austerity”, CEPR, October.
Barro Robert J. (1974), “Are
government bonds net wealth?”, Journal of Political Economy 82(6), pp.
1095-1117.
Batini Nicoletta, Giovanni Callegari and Giovanni Melina (2012), “Successful Austerity in the United States, Europe
and Japan”, IMF Working
Paper 12/190, July, Washington.
Blanchard Olivier J. (1990), “Can Severe Fiscal Contractions Be Expansionary? Tales of Two Small European Countries: A Comment”, NBER Macroeconomics Annual Vol. 5, (1990), pp. 111-116, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.
Broadbent, B. and K. Daly (2010), “Limiting the Fall-Out from Fiscal Adjustments”, Goldman Sachs Global Economics Paper 195.
Blanchard Olivier J. (1990), “Can Severe Fiscal Contractions Be Expansionary? Tales of Two Small European Countries: A Comment”, NBER Macroeconomics Annual Vol. 5, (1990), pp. 111-116, MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.
Broadbent, B. and K. Daly (2010), “Limiting the Fall-Out from Fiscal Adjustments”, Goldman Sachs Global Economics Paper 195.
Cottarelli Carlo (2012), “Fiscal Adjustment: Too Much of a
Good Thing?”, Posted on January 29 by iMFdirect.
Giavazzi Francesco and Marco Pagano (1990), “Can Severe Fiscal Contractions Be Expansionary? Tales of Two Small European Countries”, NBER
Macroeconomics Annual Vol. 5, (1990), MIT Press. Cambridge
Mass.
Giavazzi Francesco and Marco Pagano (1996) "Non-Keynesian Effects of Fiscal Policy Changes:
International Evidence and the Swedish Experience," NBER Working
Papers 5332, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.
Guajardo Jaime,
Daniel Leigh and Andrea Pescatori (2011), "Expansionary Austerity: New
International Evidence", IMF
WP/11/158, Washington. don Thomas, Michael Ash and Robert Pollin (2013), “Does High Public Debt
Consistently Stifle Economic Growth? A Critique of Reinhart and Rogoff,”
Political Economy Research Institute, Working paper n. 322, April
15, Amherst.
Irons John and Josh Bivens
(2010), “Government Debt and Economic Growth: Overreaching Claims of Debt
“Threshold” Suffer from Theoretical and Empirical Flaws”, Economic Policy
Institute, 26 July, Briefing Paper #271.
International Monetary
Fund (2010), “Will It Hurt? Macroeconomic Effects of Fiscal Consolidation.” World Economic Outlook, Chapter 3,
Washington.
International Monetary
Fund (2013), “Greece: Ex Post Evaluation of Exceptional Access Under
the 2010 Stand-By Arrangement,” June, Washington.
Kalecki Michal, (1933) Proba
teorii koniunktury [An
Essay on the Theory of Business Cycle], Instytut Koniunktury I Cen, Warsaw. As
“Outline of a theory of the of Business Cycle”, in Kalecki, 1971.
Kalecki Michal (1934), “On foreign trade and
‘Domestic Exports’”, translated from Polish in Kalecki (1971).
Kalecki Michal (1935), “A macrodynamic theory
of business cycles”, Econometrica 3,
July, pp. 327-44.
Kalecki Michal (1943),
“Political aspects of full employment”, The
Political Quarterly, p. 332-331.
Kalecki Michal (1971), Selected essays on the dynamics of the capitalist economy 1933-1970,
CUP, Cambridge.
Keynes J. Maynard (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money, London, Macmillan.
Kimball Miles and Yichuan Wang (2013), “After crunching Reinhart and Rogoff’s data, we’ve concluded that high debt does not slow growth”, QUARTZ, 29 May.
Kimball Miles and Yichuan Wang (2013), “After crunching Reinhart and Rogoff’s data, we’ve concluded that high debt does not slow growth”, QUARTZ, 29 May.
Olivier Blanchard
and Daniel Leigh, “Growth Forecast Errors and Fiscal
Multipliers,” IMF Working
Paper, January 2013.
Lucas Robert
(1976), "Econometric policy evaluation: A critique", Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy 1 (1), pp. 19–46.
Nuti Domenico M. (2004), “Kalecki
and Keynes Re-visited”, in Zdzislaw
L. Sadowski and Adam Szeworski (Eds), Kalecki’s
Economics Today, Routledge, London and New York.
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff (2010), "Growth in a Time of
Debt", NBER Working Paper No. 15639, January.
Reinhart, Carmen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff (2013),
“Responding to Our Critics”, The New York
Times, 25 April.
Robinson Joan V. (1976), “Michael Kalecki: a
neglected prophet”, New York Review of
Books, 23, 4 March, pp. 28-30.
In my answer to Branko (see Comments to this post) I wrote:
"If the size of the fiscal multiplier (which is the weighted average of the multipliers applicable to various expenditure cuts and tax rises involved) is greater than the current debt/GDP ratio, as the latest IMF researchers suggest, then fiscal consolidation raises such a ratio."
I should have written:
"If the size of the fiscal multiplier (which is the weighted average of the multipliers applicable to various expenditure cuts and tax rises involved) is greater than the inverse of the current debt/GDP ratio, as the latest IMF researchers suggest, then fiscal consolidation raises such a ratio."
A CORRECTION:
In my answer to Branko (see Comments to this post) I wrote:
"If the size of the fiscal multiplier (which is the weighted average of the multipliers applicable to various expenditure cuts and tax rises involved) is greater than the current debt/GDP ratio, as the latest IMF researchers suggest, then fiscal consolidation raises such a ratio."
I should have written:
"If the size of the fiscal multiplier (which is the weighted average of the multipliers applicable to various expenditure cuts and tax rises involved) is greater than the inverse of the current debt/GDP ratio, as the latest IMF researchers suggest, then fiscal consolidation raises such a ratio."