The
Department of Economics and Statistics of Siena University held a day-long conference in
memory of Marcello de Cecco on 17 September, which would have been his 77thbirthday.
I first met Marcello in October 1963 in Cambridge. Our dear common
friend the late Bruno Miconi, a fellow research student in economics, introduced
him to me. I already knew and appreciated Marcello from his contributions to
Mario Pannunzio’s Il Mondo,
but I found him even more impressive in person. Flamboyant, brilliant, learned,
ironical and witty, yet approachable, friendly, generous. We got on well
immediately. I have been fortunate in having him as a friend and colleague not
only in our Cambridge years but also at Siena University, at the European
University Institute in Florence, and at the Sapienza University in Rome – in almost
daily contact for a total of over 25 years out of the over 50 years of our
association.
Marcello was an alert and insatiable observer of current
economic, political and social affairs, never satisfied with simple
explanations but searching for deeper causes, enquiring “come va il fatto”. I
remember his surprise when the daily Il
Fatto Quotidiano that follows a
similar inquisitive approach was published. Bruno Miconi used to say that Marcello should have been a film scriptwriter.
A Pembroke man, Marcello was held in great esteem by his
supervisor Michael Posner; given his interests in international finance he was
also in touch with Kingsman Richard Kahn, who however suspected him (injustly)
of monetarist inclinations, because of his contacts with Chicago and Milton
Friedman. Marcello had created a considerable intellectual niche for himself
through his work on Eurodollars – dollar-denominated deposits held outside the
US, mostly in Europe, thus escaping regulation by the Federal Reserve Board
including reserve requirements. In this area at the time he knew
more than his teachers and his expertise was appreciatively recognised and
utilised in seminars and discussions. We both were invited to become members of
the Monday Group, a seminar in Economics held regularly if reservedly in
King’s. We shared an interest in the history of economic thought, indeed in a
little known Russian pioneer of mathematical economics, Vladimir K. Dmitriev;
Marcello edited the Italian version of his Economic
Essays on Value, Competition and Utility, I edited the English version.
When it became apparent that we were working on the same thing Marcello simply
said that nobody had a monopoly on that author. At a Faculty seminar we
presented a joint criticism of the Modigliani-La Malfa model of the interaction
of monetary and real aspects of the Italian balance of payments. Later we
co-operated in other research projects, especially in Florence.
Marcello was unique – among Italian students in Cambridge – in
that he had come with his Mother, not wanting to leave signora Antonietta on
her own back in his home town of Lanciano (pronounced as if written Langiano).
They looked after each other well. Somehow, in spite of linguistic obstacles
compounded by the regional variety of food nomenclature, his mother always
succeeded in securing from the butcher her desired cuts of meat. Marcello gave
the delightful account of his mother meeting Piero Sraffa in Cambridge Market
Square, when she greeted Mr Sraffa with: “I am delighted to meet you, Professor;
my son has spoken very highly of you …”. Marcello theorised the optimality of
driving only second hand cars, but he chose only beautiful comfortable large
ones, including a memorable Jaguar. When a lectureship was advertised at the
University of East Anglia, I encouraged Marcello to apply and supported his
candidature strongly. His appointment was a great success, and there, too, he
met Julia Bamford – the other great woman behind the great man – so that I
could boast of involvement in his taking both a job and a wife.
When the prospect of Italy joining the Euro began to be widely
discussed, in 1992 on the eve of the French referendum on the subject Marcello gave
enthusiastic endorsement of Italian membership. He wrote an article for Repubblica – Affari e Finanza,
entitled I
disgregati del 2003, which
marked the beginning of his long collaboration to Repubblica (18/09/1992, reprinted
in L'economia di Lucignolo, Donzelli, see Marcello’s obituary by Carlo Clericetti). In that
article Marcello described an apocalyptic picture of Italy as a member
of a Latin Union (with France, Spain, Portugal and Greece) ten years
later: backward, underdeveloped, impoverished, authoritarian, repressive, bigoted
and male-dominated; the article ends with a decrepit professor, who dares
teaching politically incorrect views about the evolution of the international
monetary system, being arrested and taken away by police. By contrast the
member states of the Mittel-European Union thrive and prosper even more than
the Anglo-American Federation, and hire the young unemployed migrants from
Italy, who send food parcels to their parents at home in spite of this being officially
frowned-upon.
Marcello’s enthusiastic endorsement of the euro was tempered, when it
actually happened, only by his disapproval of Berlusconi’s failure to contain price increases in the changeover from lira to euro, something experienced only
by Greece and there to a much smaller degree. Marcello’s enthusiasm was right:
the euro brought about significantly lower interest rates; that the fiscal
space was not used to reduce public debt and on the contrary encouraged greater
indebtedness is another matter. The euro also brought about a rate of inflation
lower than that achieved in Germany by the Bundesbank itself, and greater
European and global integration of trade and Foreign Direct Investment. It did
not bring about economic growth, but this was due to poor economic policies and
various factors both on the demand (e.g. increasing inequality) and supply
sides (productivity slowdown, etc.).
Ten years after, there was a lot to justify Marcello’s evolving
position as a Eurocritic. Austerity policies enshrined in the Treaties under
German hegemony were self-defeating and suicidal, Marcello was a Keynesian
dyed-in-the-wool and knew it well. The German trade surplus, which Marcello
attributed primarily to the post-Transition integration of Germany with Eastern
Europe regardless of the weakness or strength of the euro, contravened EU rules
but was unduly tolerated, and pushed trade deficit countries to run public
budget deficits. Improvements could have been made, even without renegotiating
the Treaties. Failure to make progress not only towards a Federal Europe
design, but even towards piece-meal improvements, justify Marcello’s latest
position as Eurosceptic, especially considering that he never indulged in
advocating Exitaly, the Italian exit from the Euro that many advocated and
still advocate lightly and unthinkingly. On the Euro, Marcello was always right.
For Marcello, the current crisis of the Euro was triggered by the
Deauville Summit of 19 October 2010 at which Angela Merkel and Nicholas Sarkozy
announced that at least part of any default on public debt would be born by
bondholders. At the time I disagreed strongly with Marcello: why should
investors who had benefited from large interest differentials, knowingly taking
the associated risk, not have to bear the entire cost of default? If worried by
that risk they could always have covered themselves as much as they wished by
buying Credit Default Swaps. Yet, with the benefit of hindsight, now I am
inclined to agree with Marcello. It was the prospect of bail-in that created
the spread and effectively split the euro area.
By displaying the richness and depth of Marcello’s contributions
of a lifetime, the Siena Conference stressed how dependent on his wisdom many
of us had become. Today I find myself often wondering what Marcello would have
said about current problems. Many Conference participants asked themselves what
he would have said about Brexit: the consensus was that his natural diffidence
towards Britain as a free rider of European integration, and the various
exemptions repeatedly negotiated by the British (no Schengen, no common
currency, the British rebate), would have led him to conclude that European
integration might have progressed and improved without Britain. But we have no
hard evidence that he would have taken that line. And we have no clue on what
view he would have taken about the European migration crisis or the Islamic
threat or the US elections with their problematic presidential candidates. It is
at difficult times like these that we miss him most.
P.S. On the Siena Conference see also contributions by Emiliano Brancaccio,
Paolo Paesani, Salvatore Settis and Carlo Clericetti.
P.S. On the Siena Conference see also contributions by Emiliano Brancaccio,
Paolo Paesani, Salvatore Settis and Carlo Clericetti.