I am grateful to Vladimir Popov of TsEMI, the Central Economics and Mathematics Institute of the Russian Academy of
Sciences, Moscow, for contributing this guest post to our Blog as an extended
comment on my previous post on Seismic
Faults in the European Union.
Vladimir Popov on: EU – Nationalism and Inequalities
“Imagine there's no countries ... And the world will be one.
It may happen, if the current rise in inequalities is reversed.
Mario Nuti predicts new difficulties for the EU and
believes Lenin was right, when stated that United States of Europe are either
impossible or reactionary (post of January 8, 2017). He may well be right, as he has been so many
times, but I wish he wasn’t.
In the EU for the first time in history member
countries voluntarily decided to eliminate borders – a dream of many since
ancient times. It was by the way also one of the staples of the communist
ideology – nations eventually, after the full victory of communism, will merge,
borders will disappear, a brotherhood of men will share the whole world. As the best poet of Soviet era Vladimir Mayakovsky put it,
“For we want this world to be a common earth
Without Latvias and without Russias”.
Many of those born and raised in the USSR cherish this
dream and admire the EU that seemed to have been able to achieve this goal
without coercion and violence. It would be most regretful, if EU project will
not succeed.
This is the moral argument in favor of the EU that
does not prove, of course, that Mario is wrong. Many inevitable trends may be
undesirable for large groups of people. Below, however, are some “hard core,
material” arguments, why current centrifugal forces in the EU and the world may
be only a temporary phenomenon.
Nationalism
and inequalities
Conservative politicians all over the world have recently spoken against
globalization. As former French Prime Minister Dominique De Villepin put it recently,
”globalization,
on the one hand, promotes cooperation, on the other hand, brought new mutual
exclusion, isolation and radicalization”. And Donald Trump wants “Americanism,
not globalism”.
It would be wrong, however, to blame globalization for
all the disasters and misfortunes, from non-growing real incomes to the rise of
nationalism. History does not repeat itself, but it rhymes. Those who blame
globalization today for economic and social misfortunes are similar to the
luddites of the XIX century that believed that the use of machines leads to the
rising unemployment and falling wages.
There are cases when globalization works leading to
rising incomes of the masses. Theoretically greater international flows of
goods, ideas and technology, capital and labor should increase productivity,
but in reality this happens only if these flows are carefully managed (Popov,
2014, Chapter 5)..
Why in some countries greater economic interaction
with the world was accompanied in recent several decades by rising income and
its relatively even distribution (China and other East Asian countries),
whereas in other countries modest growth of income coupled with rising
inequalities left large masses of
population worse off (many Western countries, including the US, Eastern
Europe and former Soviet Union)? The answer is that policy matters a great deal
and many good policies that allow gaining from globalization are often
non-orthodox and counterintuitive (Polterovich, Popov, 2005). If globalization
is accompanied by the increase in income and wealth inequalities within
countries, so that gains from globalization are appropriated by the few better
off, whereas the masses get nothing or very little, it is only too easy for the
interested political forces to blame globalization for the negative
developments.
The
central argument of this post is that the reversal of the previous trend
towards the decline in income inequalities in the last three decades in most
countries created favorable grounds for the rise of nationalist and
anti-globalization feelings (Popov, 2016). Lindert and Williamson (2016) claim that income
inequalities breed populism and attribute the rise of inequalities to
globalization (especially in the two periods of American history – Gilded Age
of the late 1800 and recent three decades since the 1980s). My argument is that
income inequalities indeed contribute to the rise of populism and nationalism,
but that globalization does not necessarily lead to the rise in inequalities.
Trends in nationalism are explained, among other factors,
by both between the countries and within the countries inequalities. If the
gains from globalization are distributed evenly, the public is willing to
embrace it, but if the gains are appropriated by few, it is easy for
nationalist political forces to turn the public against globalization.
Hence, there are several globalization models,
depending on the trend in inter and intra- country inequalities in recent three
decades:
·
Great gains from globalization for the country
as a whole and relatively small rise in within the country inequalities (Japan,
China, SEA, Scandinavian countries, the Netherlands);
·
Small
gains from globalization for the country as a whole, but decline in domestic
inequalities (some LA countries, including Brazil);
·
Large
gains from globalization for the country as a whole, but increase in domestic
inequalities (Britain and some continental European countries);
·
Small
gains from globalization for the country as a whole and increase in domestic
inequalities (US, Russia in the 1990s).
The worst conditions for the rise of nationalism would
be in the first group of countries, the best – in the last, fourth group, with
the 2nd and 3rd group falling in between.
The rise of nationalism in recent decades in the EU and many other
countries seems to be associated with the increase in within the country income
inequalities. In some countries income inequalities did not increase and
nationalist and anti-globalist feelings are more related to the slowdown of
growth and other reasons, but in most countries there was an increase in income
and wealth inequalities since the 1980s – a reversal of the trend of over 50
years that created a fertile ground for rise of nationalism (Popov, 2016).
Recent
trends in income inequalities in EU
The fall of the Berlin Wall, collapse of the USSR and the conversion of
Eastern Europe and former Soviet republics to capitalism, added additional push
to the growing income inequalities trend due to both – the disappearance of
“socialist counterbalance” for the Western capitalism and the rise in
inequalities in the transition countries of Eastern Europe and former Soviet
Union themselves (Jomo, Popov, 2016).
In most European countries income inequalities
increased since the beginning of the 1980s – the reversal of the trend that
predominated since early 20th century (fig. 1). This increase in
inequalities may be the single most important reason for the rise of
nationalism. In Eastern Europe there was a transformational recession of the
1990s associated with the transition to the market economy – output fell by
20-50% in the course of 2-5 years (Popov, 2000), which certainly contributed to
the rise of nationalism. But in Western Europe there was no major recession
(except for Greece). Even though economic growth was not very strong, it
was rather stable, recessions of 1993
(per capita GDP fell by 0.4%), 2009 (-4,7%) and 2012-13 (-0.4%) were overcome
and average incomes, unlike in the US,
by 2016 were way higher than in the 1980s. However, the progressing
unevenness in income distribution undermined real incomes and social status of
large groups of European population making them an easy target for the
nationalist politicians.
Britain may be the case in point. The rise in
nationalism is often explained by unfairness and humiliation experienced by the
whole nation (for instance, Germany after the First World War or developing
countries where costs of globalization are often higher than benefits). In Britain, however, the recent rise of
nationalism did coincide with the relatively successful economic development
and with the improvement of its economic positions versus the major
competitors. Britain was falling behind continental Western Europe in terms of
its per capita income and this trend was reversed only a decade after Britain
entered the EU (fig. 2).
However. only a minority of the population benefited
from the acceleration of economic growth since the early 1980s – income
inequalities increased (fig. 1) and so did wealth inequalities (fig. 3).
From the point of view of economic efficiency and
future growth, Brexit is bad for the EU and especially bad for Britain. But the majority of
British voters apparently blamed economic difficulties not on policies that
allowed inequalities to increase, but on the European integration and
globalization.
Future
There may be at least two
scenarios for the EU and the world. First, if the rise of income inequalities
would continue, social tensions in some countries will become unbearable and
will produce a social turmoil and anti-globalisation, nationalist sentiments.
And the rise of nationalism may lead to conflicts, if not wars, between
countries, with the collapse of the international trade and capital flows, like
in the 1930s. Then the world may once again get into the familiar 20th
century historical track and there may be a pause in or even the reversal of
globalization, like during the Great Depression, when the outburst of
protectionism led to the decline of the international trade and capital movements.
This is the worst scenario: the world degrading into social and national
conflicts.
Second, countries that
carry out successful policies of limiting inequalities would become more
competitive, driving other countries “out of anti-globalisation business”. Even
small countries, if they are successful, may create a counterbalance through
the demonstration effect to the tendency of unconstrained capitalism to cut
welfare programs and increase inequalities. These countries may regulate the
functioning of the market mechanisms through direct interventions and high
progressive taxation to reduce bubbles and windfall profits. Besides, the
crucial way of lowering inequalities is public and collective property, so it
could be expected that state enterprises, non-profit institutions, labour
managed enterprises and coops, operating not for profits, but for public good
would become more common. Such a more optimistic scenario implies that social
upheavals within countries and national conflicts between countries could be
largely avoided. EU in this case would have a bright future.
References
Facundo Alvaredo, Anthony B
Atkinson, and Salvatore Morelli (2016). Top wealth shares in the UK over more
than a century, Working Papers Department of Economics Ca’ Foscari University of
Venice No. 01 /WP/20.
Alvaredo, Facundo,
Anthony B. Atkinson, Thomas Piketty and Emmanuel Saez (2012). ‘The World Top
Incomes Database’, http://www.wid.world/#Introduction
Jomo, K.S., V. Popov (2016). Income Inequalities in
Perspective. Develoipment, No. 2,
2016.
Lindert, P. and Jeffrey Williamson (2016). Unequal Gains: American
Growth and Inequality since 1700. Princeton University Press, 2016.
Maddison
project (2013). http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/maddison-project/home.htm,
2013 version.
|
Polterovich, V.,
Popov, V. (2005). Appropriate
Economic Policies at Different Stages of Development. NES, 2005 - http://www.nes.ru/english/research/pdf/2005/PopovPolterovich.pdf.
Popov, V. (2000). Shock Therapy versus
Gradualism: The End of the Debate (Explaining the Magnitude of the
Transformational Recession) – Comparative
Economic Studies, Vol. 42, No. 1, Spring 2000, pp. 1-57 (http://www.nes.ru/%7Evpopov/documents/TR-REC-full.pdf);
Popov, V. (2014). Mixed Fortunes: An Economic History of China, Russia and the West. Oxford
University Press, April 2014.
Popov, V. (2016). Is Globalisation
Coming to an End Due to Increase of Income Inequalities? - MPRA paper
№73094 , August 2016.
World Wealth
and Income Database. http://www.wid.world/#Database:
Mario Nuti’s reply:
I agree with Vladimir that a world without borders
would be very attractive, as a realisation of both human freedom and economic
efficiency. However it is no accident that it was part of communist utopia only
after the expected universal diffusion of communism. For a world without
borders involves - as I pointed out in my previous post - global communism in
access to national social capital (however defined, whether as physical infrastructure,
social cohesion and trust, or welfare state institutions and provisions). This
is neither feasible nor desirable nor sustainable in a world where private
ownership is globally prevailing and fully protected. I take it that Vladimir
would not support unrestricted full communism – in the sense of abolition of
both private and national social property – on a global scale or even in a
single country or just in the European Union. I regard Vladimir’s
unconditional endorsement of the Schengen Area abolition of internal borders (and
neglect of external ones) not as a cogent argument in favour of a world
without borders but merely as evidence of his generous nature.
I particularly like Vladimir’s characterisation of the
relationship between globalisation and inequality, with his four country cases:
(a) large gains, small rise of inequality; (b) small gains, inequality decline;
(c) large gains, [significant] rise of inequality; (d) small gains, inequality
increase. The first case would make people approve of globalisation; the last
case would be associated with strongly nationalistic, anti-globalisation
feelings and policies; while the two intermediate cases also would
be somewhat nationalistic and anti-globalist but to a lesser extent. And at the
global level, I would add even more positively and forcefully than Vladimir,
globalisation has halved the incidence of poverty in the last twenty years –
lifting hundreds of millions of Chinese from starvation to obesity – and achieved
the reduction of inequality among the citizens of the world.
However, globalisation, including migrations, does not
lead to “gains … appropriated by the few better off, whereas
the masses get nothing or very little benefit”, as Vladimir conjectures. It does yield net
benefits, as I readily recognised, but it actually makes a
non-negligible number of people worse off. In theory we can imagine a redistribution of gross gains to gross losers so as to make everybody better off - which is how Vladimir would be able to achieve a win-win situation. But such Paretian redistribution is not possible, because it would have to be international and/or regressive. International redistribution is presently impossible for lack of political globalisation, i.e. global governance by institutions capable of global taxation and expenditure. Regressive redistribution from gainers who tend to be poorer to losers who tend to be richer would be undesirable, as I trust Vladimir would agree.
And even if everybody gained from globalisation,
inequality in the distribution of gains would legitimise some opposition to unrestricted, raw globalisation. Vladimir’s comparison with the Luddites
is very apt, but with opposite implications with respect to the one he draws:
technical progress in the early 19th century (and today’s
automation) also yields net benefits but makes some people worse off, just like
globalisation and migrations, therefore justifying – unless there was compensatory income
redistribution from gainers to losers – resistance and even forceful
opposition by the losers.
The dividing line between populism and democracy is
very thin. It is no accident that today we talk of right wing and left wing
populism. "The accusation of populism can easily become an instrument to
maintain and extend the power of oligarchies, and their influence on public
life and decisions, reducing any protest attempt from below to irrationality or
intellectual or moral laziness. Anti-populism therefore can become a
weapon in the hands of the élite, a weapon that jeopardizes the essence of
democratic coexistence. While populism, if properly articulated, may be useful
to democracy" (my translation from Lorenzo Del Savio e Matteo Mameli,
"Il populismo è democratico: Machiavelli e gli appetiti delle élite"
2014), whose conclusions are based on a recent debate on Machiavelli's theses
in his Discorsi sopra la prima deca di Tito Livio. http://ilrasoiodioccam-micromega.blogautore.espresso.repubblica.it/files/2014/02/machiavelli-populismo.pdf.
Though growing support for populist parties is also due to non-economic
factors, such as the feeling of marginalisation, of a falling standing in
society, of having lost control over one’s condition, determined by the
establishment élite; there are also cultural, ethnic and religious diversities
coming into play. When these factors determine electoral choice there is no
reason to dismiss the results as expression of populism instead of an integral
part and parcel of a democratic system.
Vladimir offers two alternative visions of the future.
A pessimistic scenario involves rising inequalities and anti-globalist
policies, the rise of nationalisms with possible commercial or even hot
conflicts, a pause or even reversal of globalisation. An optimistic vision,
favoured by Vladimir, involves the containment of inequality, the restoration
of the welfare state funded by progressive taxation, the build-up of public and
collective enterprises (including self-managed non-profit cooperatives). “The
EU in this case would have a bright future” – he writes. Unfortunately there
are other fault lines in the EU today, which I tried to spell out in my post
and are left unscathed by Vladimir’s reflections, which do not alter my
fundamental pessimism.