This
was my answer to Grzegorz Kolodko, Poland’s Minister of Finance and First
Deputy Premier for the Economy (1994-97 and 2002-03), when in the mid-‘90s he
asked me – his adviser sponsored by the European Commission – for an opinion on
the feasibility and desirability of introducing a flat tax. I recommended instead a reduction of indirect
taxation and the introduction of a tax on capital gains. To his credit Grzegorz
listened to me on the flat tax, he reduced the number and level of marginal tax
rates but at the same time he raised public expenditure on investment and on re-distribution,
introduced an industrial policy that did not seek to pick winners but promoted
high value added and export activities, and his package worked well.
The
introduction of a flat tax has become a major issue in the policy discussions
on the eve of Italian elections, as it is being vigorously propounded by Silvio
Berlusconi and the leaders of his right-wing coalition. My views on the flat
tax have not changed at all in the the intervening years.
There
are two main arguments in favour of a flat tax:
1)
the presumed existence of a Laffer curve, whereby government tax revenue is
supposed to rise with the increase of the tax rate up to a maximum, beyond
which a higher tax rate would actually reduce tax revenue, and
2)
lower taxation would encourage the emergence of activities that at present
evade taxation, and therefore raise additional government revenue in that way.
According
to established legend (Wanniski 1978) in 1974 Arthur Laffer, then a professor
at Chicago University, drew the curve named after him, depicting tax revenue as
a function of the tax rate, on a napkin at a dinner in a Washington restaurant to
illustrate the effects of President Ford’s tax cuts. Except that he did not
draw it on the basis of empirical evidence, but simply noting that for a zero
tax rate tax revenue would obviously be zero, and assuming that for a 100% tax
rate there would be a zero revenue because nobody would work or invest for a
zero after-tax return. He also presumed that there would be a continuous parabolic
shaped curve in between those two points and drew a maximum around a 50% tax
rate. Thus you could obtain the same tax revenue with a low tax rate on a large
tax basis or with a high tax rate on a smaller basis.
Laffer
(2004) acknowledged that already in the 14th century the Tunisian philosopher Ibn
Khaldun had noticed this possibility, which had also been asserted by many
other thinkers including Keynes: “… taxation may be so high … that … a
reduction of taxation will run a better chance than an increase of balancing
the budget” (quoted by Laffer).
The
trouble is that actual empirical estimates of revenue-maximizing tax rates have
varied widely, with a mid-range of around 70% (Fullerton 2008, which fits with the
“so high rate” stipulated by Keynes), while current tax rates in OECD countries
average about half that rate. So much so that the IMF Fiscal Monitor of October 2017 actually recommends raising tax
rates in a progressive fashion in order to reduce current excessive inequality of
income and wealth, for “There is little evidence that increased progressivity
reduces growth”.
More
importantly, a 100% flat tax rate is plainly silly, for a progressive tax can
reach fairly high marginal rates, historically even 90% and higher, without
ever yielding a zero tax revenue. Indeed it has been argued that the Laffer
curve might well be increasing monotonically, and in any case even a flat tax
of 100% might yield substantial revenue in special circumstances like wartime
or even in normal times depending on behavioural assumptions.
As
for the second argument in favour of a flat tax, there is absolutely no
evidence that a low tax rate – flat or not – encourages the payment of taxes
otherwise evaded at higher rates. And why should it, as Schumpeter put it there
is no good reason for anybody not reaping a benefit just because it is small.
Critics
of a flat tax lament its lack of progressiveness. Supporters – such as Berlusconi – are quick
to point out that in most OECD countries, including Italy, there already is a
flat tax on capital incomes, at a constant rate lower than the higher
progressive rates on earned incomes, so that a uniform flat tax levied at an
intermediate rate would be more progressive than the current system. And anyway
the presence of a tax-exempt threshold maintains a degree of progressiveness,
as required for instance by the Italian Constitution, art. 53; “The tax system
shall be progressive”.
These answers to critics of the flat tax lack of progressiveness are not
good enough, because the first comma of art. 53 states also that “Every person shall contribute to public expenditure in
accordance with their capability”. The progressiveness
of a flat tax is minimal, depending exclusively on the size of the tax-free
initial threshold, and may be regarded rightly as constitutionally inadequate: the
average tax rate rises slowly approaching gradually from below the flat fixed rate
on taxable income, and significant progressiveness would only be achieved for extremely
large tax-free thresholds, counterproductive for tax revenue. The corresponding
reduction in the current progressive tax on earned income would not benefit
ordinary workers but only overpaid managers, making after-tax distribution of
earned incomes more unequal. While the reduction of current excessively high
levels of public debt, as well as the reduction of excessive degrees of
inequality of income and wealth, are best served by a genuinely more
progressive tax system of the kind recommended by the IMF (2017).
On 24 January last the Washington
Post reported that Mike Hughes, a 61-year limo driver from California and a
flat-Earth strong believer, has been planning to launch a self-built rocket to
propel himself 52 miles into space in order to be able to see for himself that
the Earth is flat, for “in many months of research I’ve not been able to prove
otherwise” – he said. The trouble is that the project would cost 2 million
dollars to finance the building and fuelling of the rocket, a space-suit and a
hot-air balloon (Mike Hughes is a bit vague about his logistics), and he was
only able to raise $8,000 from GoFundMe. As he now has a fellow flat-Earther in
billionaire Silvio Berlusconi, it would be best for Silvio to fund the project
in exchange for a lift in the same rocket, and all will end well both in
California and in Italy, in the best of all possible worlds.
Addendum 1
Trabandt and Uhlig (2019) estimate the Laffer curves for labour taxation and capital income taxation for the US, the EU-14 and individual European countries for 1995-2007. They find that the US can increase tax revenues by 30% by raising labour taxes and 6% by raising capital income taxes. For the EU-14 they obtain 8% and 1% respectively. Germany could raise 10% more tax revenues by raising labour taxes but only 2% by raising capital taxes. The same numbers for France are 5% and 0%, for Italy 4% and 0% and for Spain 13% and 2%. Only Denmark and Sweden are on the “wrong” side of the Laffer curve for capital income taxation.
Addendum 2
In the latest Italian elections the Lega proposed a Flat Tax at 15% over the €7,000 tax-free threshold (plus minor further exemptions on households), while Berlusconi proposed its introduction at 23%. According to the Lega their flat tax would create an initial shortfall of €63bn (i.e. €103bn tax revenue from households and €18bn from companies instead of the combined current tax revenue of €184bn from IRPEF-IRES).
They propose to cover this shortfall first of all from 25 expenditure cuts and additional taxes (including €5bn savings on centralised public procurement, €2,5bn on military expenditure, €5bn tax increase on gas prospection, €900mn from abolition of interest charges deduction by banks and insurance companies, €800mn for official cars abolition for hospitals, €700mn cuts in "golden pensions" (of dubious constitutionality). The bulk of the coverage would come, however, from the emergence of the black economy, reduced tax evasion, additional VAT and income tax on additional transactions and incomes expected from the tax reduction. Pie in the sky.
Addendum 1
Trabandt and Uhlig (2019) estimate the Laffer curves for labour taxation and capital income taxation for the US, the EU-14 and individual European countries for 1995-2007. They find that the US can increase tax revenues by 30% by raising labour taxes and 6% by raising capital income taxes. For the EU-14 they obtain 8% and 1% respectively. Germany could raise 10% more tax revenues by raising labour taxes but only 2% by raising capital taxes. The same numbers for France are 5% and 0%, for Italy 4% and 0% and for Spain 13% and 2%. Only Denmark and Sweden are on the “wrong” side of the Laffer curve for capital income taxation.
Addendum 2
In the latest Italian elections the Lega proposed a Flat Tax at 15% over the €7,000 tax-free threshold (plus minor further exemptions on households), while Berlusconi proposed its introduction at 23%. According to the Lega their flat tax would create an initial shortfall of €63bn (i.e. €103bn tax revenue from households and €18bn from companies instead of the combined current tax revenue of €184bn from IRPEF-IRES).
They propose to cover this shortfall first of all from 25 expenditure cuts and additional taxes (including €5bn savings on centralised public procurement, €2,5bn on military expenditure, €5bn tax increase on gas prospection, €900mn from abolition of interest charges deduction by banks and insurance companies, €800mn for official cars abolition for hospitals, €700mn cuts in "golden pensions" (of dubious constitutionality). The bulk of the coverage would come, however, from the emergence of the black economy, reduced tax evasion, additional VAT and income tax on additional transactions and incomes expected from the tax reduction. Pie in the sky.
REFERENCES
Fullerton Don (2008). "Laffer curve", In
Durlauf Steven N., Lawrence E. Blume, The
New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2nd ed.), https://doi.org/10.1057%2F9780230226203.0922
International Monetary Fund IMF (2017), Fiscal Monitor: Tackling Inequality,
October.
Laffer Arthur B. (2004), “The Laffer Curve: Past,
Present, and Future”, 1 June, Backgrounder #1765, The
Heritage Foundation, https://web.archive.org/web/20071201225944/http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/bg1765.cfm
Selk Avi and Amy B. Wang (2018), “Can this flat-Earther’s long-delayed
rocket launch be saved? We may soon find out.” The Washington Post, 24 January, https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/speaking-of-science/wp/2018/01/24/can-this-flat-earthers-long-delayed-rocket-launch-be-saved-we-may-soon-find-out/?utm_term=.5a9d7e82d352
Trabandt Mathias and Harald Uhlig (2010), “How far are we from the slippery slope? The laffer curve re-visited”, ECB Working Paper Series No. 1174, April, Frankfurt, https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/ pdf/scpwps/ecbwp1174.pdf?344d6 e77a58718332bd900b10e4d85b2
Trabandt Mathias and Harald Uhlig (2010), “How far are we from the slippery slope? The laffer curve re-visited”, ECB Working Paper Series No. 1174, April, Frankfurt, https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/