One of the
factors that have slowed down Italian growth in the current crisis, even
relatively to a sluggish Eurozone, is undoubtedly the endemic accumulation of
large scale arrears in Public Administration payments to enterprises for their
supply of goods and services to central and local government. True, the very
expectation of payment delays tends to be built into enterprise costs and
therefore inflate the volume of public expenditure, but even so the build-up of
arrears remains a sick anomaly in any market economy, which especially in a
tight credit market such as at present can drive even healthy, successful
enterprises to lay-offs and bankruptcy.
The very
scale of such public arrears is uncertain, which makes it worse. A year ago the
Bank of Italy estimated the commercial debt of the Public Administration to be
of the order of €90 bn at the end of 2012. Since then €24 bn have been
paid off, but there have been new gross additions to the total. A conservative
estimate of current arrears is above €80 bn (La Repubblica, Economia e
Finanza, 10 March 2014, p.2) while estimates by the Confederation of
Italian Industry put them at as much as €120 bn. Many of the arrears involve
off-budget, non-certified expenditures.
The
idiosyncracy, not to say the idiocy of the “internal” Growth and Stability Pact
constraints, translating Maastricht macroeconomic constraints into local
authorities’ microeconomics, often prevents payments even when expenditures are
properly budgeted for and finance is available. Anal retention on the part of
high officials of the Ministry of the Economy and Finance, also in order to
avoid possible accusations of payments breaking European constraints, is an
additional factor. But an accounting convention that wholly or partly reckons
expenditures and revenues on a cash basis (“bilancio di cassa) rather than on
accrual (i.e. including also receivables and payables, as in the “bilancio di
competenza”) actually provides an incentive for the Public Administration to
obtain, as it were, free credit from enterprises in a way that does not affect
adversely its financial performance, regardless of the massive costs inflicted
as a result on the economy and its viability and growth.
Clearly from
a substantive viewpoint it makes no difference whether the Public
Administration owns given arrears to enterprises, or borrows from banks or the
financial markets an equivalent amount to pay them off, in which case it does
not augment its debt but simply transfers it from the enterprises to new
creditors. Financial markets are most unlikely to respond adversely to the
Public Administration reducing payments arrears through additional borrowing. But
with cash accounting the arrears are not counted as part of expenditure or as a
component of debt, whereas the equivalent borrowing does in its entirety. Hence
the incentive to let arrears grow.
The
popularity of cash accounting belongs to a past in which the control of
the money supply in order to control inflation was a paramount
preoccupation at all costs, even if the accumulation of Public Administration
arrears towards enterprises involved the collapse of the real economy.
This
accounting convention has already made immense damage in the course of
post-socialist transition in the early 1990s, when the International Monetary
Fund made monthly disbursements to Russia conditional on its respect of cash
limits to the state budget deficits, thus encouraging the explosion of arrears
owed to enterprises. or owed to state employees, or even to old age pensioners.
As the Russians used to say, “Pay As You Go” then meant: First you pay, then
you go. Italian so called “esodati”, whose entitlement to pension matured through
early retirement was vanified by the sudden rise of pensionable age decreed by
the indefensible, unconscionable Minister of Labour Elsa Fornero of the Monti
government, could choose this as their motto.
Such an obtuse and nonsensical
policy fostered by the IMF in Russia in the early 1990s, in addition to an
interest rate positive and large in real terms up to usury levels, and an
associated overvalued exchange rate, led to mass unemployment and the parallel
accumulation of inter-enterprise debt of the order of 40% of manufacturing
enterprises turnover. This de-monetisation of the economy was one of the most
important factors in the transformation recession of Russia in the 1990s, which
destroyed more than one third of Russian GDP. By the same token the build-up of
arrears is one of the factors that took current Italian recession above the
European and Eurozone average.
Moreover,
accounting conventions differ in Italy and Europe, and for different items of
expenditure. Capital account expenditures (perhaps 20% of total arrears, though
the precise proportions are also unknown) are always accounted for on a cash
basis, both in Europe and in the “internal” so-called Growth and Stability
Pact. Current account expenditures (the remaining roughly 80% of arrears), on
the contrary, are accounted for on an accrual basis by Europe, and on a cash
basis according to the “internal” Pact. Thus past current account expenditures,
already accounted by Europe on accrual, can be paid without impacting the
European 3% deficit ceiling in the payment year, having been accounted for
already in the deficits of past years; whereas capital account payments in 2014
count against the deficit ceiling in that same year.
Franco
Bassanini (President of the Cassa Deposity e Prestiti,
CDDPP, a public agency managing postal savings, funding infrastructure and
public enterprises) and Marcello Messori (Rome LUISS University) worked out for
the ASTRID Foundation a clever and simple method for getting rid of all Public
Administration payment arrears, both on capital and current account, without
infringing expenditure and deficit (and therefore debt) ceilings.
Namely, Public Administrations would be asked to verify, and either challenge or certify within a period of 2-3 months, any claims of payment arrears by commercial suppliers. Certified credits would be guaranteed by the state (guarantees being a contingent quasi-fiscal liability of the state, not accounted for as expenditure) and could therefore be discounted by banks at a small premium (of 1%-2%, and anyway under 2% for the credit to continue to enjoy the state guarantee). Banks would have an incentive to accept them because they could always use them as collateral with the ECB to obtain liquidity, and moreover would improve the position of Public Administrations towards the banks themselves. Beneficiary enterprises could in turn reduce their liabilities towards suppliers, invest and hire new employees. VAT owed on unpaid arrears and currently suspended would also be paid, providing additional government revenue. J.P. Morgan calculated that in Spain, which was suffering from a similar predicament and paid off about €30 bn of Public Administration commercial debts, GDP grew by 1.2% as a result; in Italy the impact on growth could be greater. (See the interview with Franco Bassanini in La Repubblica, 10 March).
On 18 March
2013 EU Vice-Presidents Antonio Tajani and Olli Rehn had already accepted that
“attenuating factors could be applied to the liquidation of commercial arrears”
from the view point of the Growth and Stability Pact, but the principle was
implemented only partially, thus involving the Ministry of the Economy and
Finance in complex intermediation to establish eligibility and priorities, that
slowed down the reduction of arrears. And last summer amendments removing state
guarantees and establishing undetermined ceilings to arrears reduction stopped
payments altogether under Enrico Letta’s government.
In a recent
TV programme Franco Bassanini declared that current account arrears (which he
put at between €20 bn and €100 bn) could be specifically removed from the
“internal” Growth and Stability Pact, having been already included in past
deficits, and paid by next June, while capital account arrears (of between €5bn
and €10 bn) could be paid by 21 September as announced by the new Premier
Matteo Renzi. Public Administrations without the necessary funds could take a
5-year loan guaranteed by the state, which in case of insolvency would be
acquired by the CDDPP, on a longer maturity basis of the order of 15 years. More power to his elbow.
3 comments:
Maybe the unpaid pension entitlements of so-called "esodati" should also be certified, guaranteed by the state and transferable to banks at a small discount?
For repeated relatively small monthly payments the transaction costs involved might turn out to be too high, perhaps prohibitive.
But certainly the pension credits of the "esodati" should be included under Public Administration arrears and perhaps given priority over PA commercial debt towards enterprises.
When Premier Matteo Renzi presented the Council of Ministers’ measures on income tax and Public Administration arrears, he estimated residual arrears at €68bn (91bn estimated by the Bank of Italy at 31/12/2011, not at 31/12/2012 as I had written, minus €22bn paid off by previous governments). It follows that VAT payable on those arrears should be about €5bn.
The Confederation of Italian Artisans of Mestre estimates residual arrears at €100bn, because the earlier estimate excluded enterprises below 20 employees, amounting to 98% of the total. They estimate VAT payable on total arrears at something like €8.5 bn.
Post a Comment