Si vis pacem, para bellum – If you want peace, prepare for war, said Vegetius
in the 5th-6th century b.C. Just as then, and by the same token, Si vis euro, para exitum: if you want to keep the euro, prepare for exit.
In 2012 Willem H. Buiter and Ebrahim Rahban, respectively chief economist and global economist of Citygroup, writing in the Market Insight section of the Financial Times (Greece far from safe even after debt swap, 13 February), coined the word Grexit – a euphonic synthetic neo-logism for Greek exit from the Eurozone. They wrote then:
In 2012 Willem H. Buiter and Ebrahim Rahban, respectively chief economist and global economist of Citygroup, writing in the Market Insight section of the Financial Times (Greece far from safe even after debt swap, 13 February), coined the word Grexit – a euphonic synthetic neo-logism for Greek exit from the Eurozone. They wrote then:
“There is some good news. Plentiful ECB liquidity has
pushed back the risk of disorderly default of systemically important euro area
banks and, combined with financial repression in euro periphery nations, has
eliminated the near-term risk of a disorderly default by a systemically
important sovereign. The external damage caused by a Greek euro area exit (or
‘Grexit’, as we call it) could, given appropriate policy response from the ECB
and euro area creditor countries, be limited and need not trigger waves of
“exit fear contagion” to other fiscally weak peripheral countries. The second
LTRO on February 29 may buy more time but until the fundamental drivers of the
euro area sovereign debt and banking crises are addressed, volatility will
remain a constant companion and recovery and growth absent friends”
Since the
unexpected victory of Alexis Tsipras and his Syriza Party, elected on 25 January
2015 on a programme rejecting European austerity and its embodiment the
Memorandum imposed by the Troika (EC, ECB and IMF) on the Samaras government,
references to Grexit have become increasingly frequent, including its variation
Grexident (Wolfgang Schauble) to
indicate the possibility of Greek “accidental” exit, in spite of neither the
Greek government nor European authorities (perhaps not including Schauble) actually
wanting to provoke that event.
Three observations
are in order.
1) There are serious legal
problems involved in Grexit.
For a start, there
is no legal provision in the Treaties for an EMU member state to withdraw from
or be compelled to leave the Eurozone. The decision to introduce the euro is
“irrevocable” (Art. 140 TFEU). The same
was true for the EU as well. Article 50 TEU, however, grants EU member states
the right to withdraw from the European Union. It is inconceivable, though it
has not been explitly stated, that a country could leave the EU and still
maintain all the rights reserved to EMU members. Conversely, membership of the
EMU is part of the obligations of membership, the so-called acquis communautaire, unless a
derogation had been successfully negotiated in 1992 at the time of signing the
Maastricht Treaty. Therefore a State
that left EMU or, by some unspecified measure, was no longer a member of EMU
would have to leave the EU as unable to fulfil its membership requirements. And even if a country was allowed such a
derogation ex-post, thus maintaining
EU membership, it would still be subject to the fiscal straightjacket of the
so-called Growth and Stability Pact and the Fiscal Compact, i.e. the exit from
EMU would not restore a country’s fiscal sovereignty. Unilateral exit from the EU would take effect
only two years after its declaration, but we must presume that exit from the EU
of an EMU member would involve its immediate exit from the Monetary Union. The immediate implementation of capital
controls and ceilings on cash withdrawals from banks, in order to avoid capital
flight and bank runs, would certainly follow. That the Council, the European
Parliament and the relevant Greek institutions would have to be consulted
beforehand would also and detrimentally make secrecy impossible.
2) Grexit would involve the
problems of managing the new currency.
The rate of
conversion of the old into the new currency would have to be identical, at
least to start with, with the rate of conversion of euro prices and wages into
the new currency. Without loss of generality therefore at time 0 the new
currency could be initially issued at par with the euro. Immediately afterwards, however, the exchange
rate between the old euro and the new currency, let us call it the drachma,
would necessarily have to be floating, fully determined by the market. At any
managed exchange rate different from the market rate Gresham's Law would operate: “Bad
money [i.e. the currency overvalued with respect to the market rate] drives
out good [the undervalued currency]”. One of the oldest economic
discoveries, anticipated in 1519 by Copernicus, even earlier by Nicole Oresme
in the fourteenth century, the law was first stated clearly by Aristophanes in
his play The Frogs, around the end of the fifth century b.C.
The new currency
would have to be devalued, very soon after issue, for the exiting country to
obtain the benefits of greater international competitiveness and devaluation of
debt payable in that currency. (Wolfgang
Munchau expects the new currency to continue to circulate at par with the euro
voluntarily on a significant scale, but this is unrealistic). However the
currency to be used for discharging earlier obligations cannot be chosen at
will; it is determined by the law of the country where the transaction has
taken place. Thus, for instance, much
and probably most of the outstanding import and export orders, as well as past
unpaid tax, and the servicing of already existing debt will have to continue to
take place in euro, under penalty of default; overall, something like 30% of
debt and almost all of derivatives trade. Target 2 large balances – a purely
technical construct while the euro lasts – would become real and would have to
be settled or canceled, coming to a head.
And furthermore “Dual currencies are
always a bad idea” (this Blog, 10 February 2010).
Euro denominated
obligations contracted under the law of a non-Eurozone country like Britain
will have to be discharged by converting the new currency into euros at the market
exchange rate. Thus the introduction of
the new currency would not avoid default, it would simply be the form that a
default would take. As well, a default
would involve the inability to access international financial markets for the
next 10 or 15 years and/or a much higher cost of finance.
The devaluation of
the new currency would necessarily involve an acceleration in inflation with
respect to euro inflation, and therefore an increase in the interest rate with
respect to euro rates, and especially a higher spread with respect to German
Bunds. The impact of the new currency on external accounts, income and
employment, will depend both on its subsequent impact (“pass-through”) on the
path of wages and prices inflation, and on trade elasticities of both demand
and supply; in principle perverse effects cannot be ruled out. In the end the success of a euro exit would
depend on the flexibility of real wages and prices, as well as on the country’s
ability to implement productivity-enhancing policies, which are the same
conditions under which the maintenance of a common currency would work.
3) Grexit would never be accidental.
Grexit would be
the result of a deliberately destructive strategy adopted by Germany and the
Nordic countries (Finland, the Netherlands, France, the Baltics) aided and
abetted by Spain and Portugal for fear of opposition parties ousting their
governments should Syriza’s example succeed, and by Italy out of perceived
self-interest. The Greek refusal, backed
by the new elected government and today reportedly supported by 80% of the Greek
population, to continue with the self-defeating, ruinous austerity policies
imposed from Brussels, Frankfurt, Berlin and Washington, is a completely
rational and democratic choice rather than the reckless strategy in an irresponsiblee
game of “chicken” of which Greece has been accused.
The most likely
course of events leading to Grexit would be: the continued denial of Greek
access to any of the €7.2bn residual funds provided by the Troika’s earlier
rescue package, while Troika officials slowly verify compliance with outdated
conditions, impossible for a poor country to satisfy; the continued prohibition
by the ECB of the Greek government raising finance through the issue of short
term Treasury bills, indeed the imposition of ceilings on banks’ holdings of
such bills, under the pretext that in Greek circumstances this would amount to
funding the government deficit directly (a peculiar dysfunction of the ECB,
seeing that the independent Bank of England and the independent Central Bank of
Japan are allowed to fund government deficits all the time).
At the end of
March the Greek government is facing a bill of €1.7bn for wages and pensions;
on 9 April the IMF is owed a loan repayment of €450mn, and in mid-April two
Treasury bills for a total of €2.4bn also are due for repayment.
Since the elections of 25 January Greek
corporations and households have cut their tax payments drastically; a
government running a primary surplus, even at the reduced rate of 1.5% of GDP, should
always be able to finance current public expenditure but now the position is
unclear. The Greek government has been
particularly skilled at mobilizing cash belonging to the National Health
Service and state-owned corporations to keep the government afloat. But cash withdrawals from the banks have been
accelerating since the new year, both before and after the elections. According to Barclays on Wednesday 18 March
withdrawals reached a record €300mn per day, at which rate they regarded a
block on deposits as unavoidable (not least because of this kind of malicious
rumour). The Greek government has
admitted that without fresh funds they will not be able to meet all payments
due in April: we should believe them.
Failure to repay the IMF loan instalment would not have immediate
adverse implications, but would involve the loss of all IMF credits. Failure to repay the €2.4bn Treasury bills
would trigger-off cross-default clauses in other loans and precipitate a deeper
crisis, including the likely loss of ECB Emergency Liquidity Assistance. At that point a run on the banks, stricter
limits on bank withdrawals, capital controls and actual default would become
self-fulfilling prophecies. In order to
avoid the de-monetisation of the economy and its vast contractionary
implications the government would be forced to issue a euro substitute, i.e. a new
currency parallel to the Euro.
The transition to
the new currency presumes that the new banknotes and coins can be produced
quickly or, better, well in advance in complete secrecy. Normally this would
take about six months; it has been suggested that the new currency could be introduced
by stamping old euro notes as drachmas, but this would be a silly waste of good
money.However a cash shortage could be initially
tackled by means of the issue of small denomination Treasury notes, or by the
issue of bank cheques like those that were introduced in Italy in the 1980s to
deal with a shortage of coinage. At least initially, and indeed for some time,
the euro and the new currency would circulate in parallel, but as long as the
rate of exchange between the two was market determined this should not create
problems other than some confusion and uncertainty.
It might be safest to turn our deposits into bricks and mortar, withdraw as much cash as we can as fast as we can while we still can, and hide it under the mattress to avoid negative interest rates. Actually, si vis pacem para pacem, as Pope Francis might have said, and if you want to keep the Euro get on with completing a banking Union, promote fiscal and political integration; above all Growth and Stability suicide Pact must be imaginatively re-interpreted and accompanied by a serious, large scale, European public investment effort. Together with the felicitous large reduction in oil price, overdue but welcome Quantitative Easing by the ECB and substantial euro de-valuation, this might still do the trick without the drama and trauma of Eurozone and European Union dis-integration.
It might be safest to turn our deposits into bricks and mortar, withdraw as much cash as we can as fast as we can while we still can, and hide it under the mattress to avoid negative interest rates. Actually, si vis pacem para pacem, as Pope Francis might have said, and if you want to keep the Euro get on with completing a banking Union, promote fiscal and political integration; above all Growth and Stability suicide Pact must be imaginatively re-interpreted and accompanied by a serious, large scale, European public investment effort. Together with the felicitous large reduction in oil price, overdue but welcome Quantitative Easing by the ECB and substantial euro de-valuation, this might still do the trick without the drama and trauma of Eurozone and European Union dis-integration.
24 comments:
Would Greece actually be allowed to issue a parallel currency?
Once Greece has lost access to aid and ECB Emergency Liquidity Assistance they would have nothing to lose, they could not be fined or threatened with anything. No way a parallel currency could be stopped. And that would be equivalent to a de facto exit.
Would the Eurozone become more manageable if the Germans and the Nordic countries left and set up their own strong euro, while the Southern countries kept but made it weaker?
And just how would you propose to "imaginatively re-interpret" the suicidal Growth and Stability Pact? With a bit of creative accounting??
It has been suggested - among others by George Soros - that the Germans should leave rather than the Southern members.
This of course would leade to rapid appreciation of the new DM, just as it happened to the Swiss Frank once the Swiss Central Bank abandoned the peg to the euro.
German net exports and therefore income and employment would suffer. Germany has no incentive to do this. Much better to be in a position to enjoy superior competitiveness and bully the rest of Europe.
How to re-interpret imaginatively the GSP? There are genuine and not simply cosmetic possible improvements,
For instance:
- remove public investments from the calculation of government deficit;
-treat government borrowing for the purpose of paying off arrears owed to government suppliers as a change of creditor and not as an increase in debt;
- calculate potential income like the OECD does.
These measures alone would promote Eurozone growth as if by magic.
"the transition to the new currency presumes that the new banknotes and coins can be produced quickly or, better, well in advance in complete secrecy."
There is another way, following Milosevic example. Since the end of 1990 Milosevic, reacting to the "austerity" policy of the Markovic federal government instructed the Bank of Serbia to create dinars without the authorization of the Yugoslav Federation Central Bank. This led to the failure of Markovic stabilization policy and to the dissolution of Yugoslavia. Eventually the rate of inflation, which had reached 60% before Markovic, reached with Milosevic astronomical levels. What Tsipras could do is simply to let the Central Bank of Greece create euro balances and print autonomously Euros (as ìt does presently on behalf of the ECB).
Sure, the Central Bank of Greece could create euro balances, but its ability to print euro banknotes is strictly limited.
It is true that only 8% of banknotes are printed by the ECB, while the remaining 92% are printed by the national Central Banks of Eurozone member states, but the stock and circulation of banknotes are closely monitored and controlled by the ECB.
1) The total amount of banknotes to be printed at any time is authorized by the ECB;
2) Each national Central Bank can only print a share of the 92% of euro banknotes authorized by the ECB proportional to its ECB shareholding;
3) Each NCB is responsible for the production of certain denominations assigned by the ECB; for instance in 2014 Greece only was enabled to print (directly or through a specialized printer, national or foreign) €5 and €10 banknotes, identified with the letter Y in their serial number.
Therefore the the Central Bank of Greece could not print euro banknotes at will.
You say that Italy is not supporting Greece out of "perceived self-interest", but surely Italy can only gain from Troika generosity towards Greece and the promotion of European policies of investment and growth?
Yes, Nico, but evidently Italy's exposure to €40bn Greek bonds going toxic is regarded by Matteo Renzi - probably wrongly, and in spite of his rhetoric - as a more tangible loss from Grexit than the uncertain indirect advantages of an unlikely European policy change towards investment and growth.
If Greece did issue a parallel currency, would this decision be difficult to reverse?
Not at all, the measure could be easily reversed. Preferably - if the parallel currency was successful in improving competitiveness and reduce debt - after it had recovered the parity with the euro. Or at any time at the market rate of exchange prevailing after the announcement of imminent re-conversion back to the euro.
Almost half a billion due for repayment by Greece to the IMF on 9 April. And Tsipras meeting Putin in Moscow on 8 April. Will good old uncle Vladimir sign him a fat cheque?
So the Greek Central Bank is only allowed to print €5 and €10 notes. Perhaps they should be allowed only to mint 1 and 2 cents coins.
Not the best time to ask Russia for financial support, in view of the low oil price, Ukrainian sanctions, rouble devaluation and the large fall in Gosbank reserves. But there is still a lot of fat, and half a billion is nothing among friends.
You are right, “Si vis pacem, para pacem” does sound like something Pope Francis might have said, but as a matter of fact the dictum was coined by Barthélemy Prosper Enfantin, described as an early French socialist and one of the founders of Saint-Simonianism, as early as 2 April 1841, with reference to the war with Algeria.
Thanks. Amazing. Nihil Novi sub sole.
It has been claimed that "Berlin actually encouraged the Papandreou regime in 2009 to exaggerate the size of Greece’s debt hole", see https://hat4uk.wordpress.com/2015/04/09/greek-debt-repudiation-is-varoufakis-about-to-make-a-distinction-between-borrowing-obligations-and-odious-debt/.
Is that a credible story?
It is certainly credible, Schauble and Papandreu are capable of anything. But we will never know whether it the story is true.
So, what is going to happen next? Has Grexit been averted or is it still in the cards?
Anything could happen. Greece has paid the $450mn or so that it owed the IMF on 9 April, much to everybody's relief, but there still are €2.4bn worth of Treasury Bonds also falling due shortly. Plus €203mn on 1 May and €770mn on 12 May and €1.6bn in June all to the IMF.
It all impinges on whether the Troika will decide that Greece has undertaken or is credibly committed to the structural reforms (pension cuts, labour dismissals and privatisations) on which the release of the residual €7.2bn bail-out funds were conditional.
Without access to these €7.2bn Greece is likely to default on its payments to the IMF. This does not involve exit automatically but in practice it would, through the cessation of access to ECB Emergency Liquidity Assistance, Bank runs, likely issue of a substitute currency etc.
Only time will tell. We will know soon enough.
Two pieces of bad news in today’s FT raise the probability of Greece defaulting in May.
Apparently Greek officials have approached informally the IMF proposing to delay the repayment of loans due in May and June (see previous comment) but were told that no rescheduling was possible; indeed they were persuaded not to make that request officially, presumably to avoid an open refusal.
At the same time Germany’s finance minister Wolfgang Schäuble is reported to have virtually ruled out, in an interview, that at the Eurogroup meeting in Riga on 24 April a deal might release bailout funds to Athens. "You can't spend hundreds of billions... in a bottle without a bottom."
However Die Zeit reports that Ms Merkel now might support emergency measures that would give Greece continued access to ECB Emergency Financial Assistance even in case of default. It is diffisult to believe that ECB rules can be made so flexible, even by Ms M.
The writing is on the wall:
“The European Central Bank is studying measures to rein in Emergency Liquidity Assistance to Greek banks, as resistance to further aiding the country’s stricken lenders grows in the Governing Council” (BloombergBusiness 21/04/2015).
"Bleak in Greece. Athens’ chances of striking a deal to access a much-needed EUR7.2bn in rescue aid looked even worse on Sunday after Alexis Tsipras, prime minister, accused bailout monitors of making "absurd" demands and seeking to impose "harsh punishment" on Athens." (FT, 1 June)
Post a Comment